MCD2020 Microeconomics 微观经济 assignment 代写

  • 100%原创包过,高质代写&免费提供Turnitin报告--24小时客服QQ&微信:120591129
  • MCD2020 Microeconomics 微观经济 assignment 代写


    © Monash College
    Page 1 of 8
    MCD2020 Microeconomics
    Trimester 2, 2017
    Research Assignment
    Word limit: 1000 words (must be stated)
    Weightage: 10%
    Due Date: Week 9 – Friday August 25th 2017 10 am
    Instructions to Students
    1. Learning Objectives:
    This assessment task is designed to build independent research, analytical and
    writing skills. It is an individual task.
    2. Submission requirements:
    It must be submitted typed, one-sided, and double spaced on white A4 paper. Work
    submitted for assessment must be accompanied by a completed copy of the Cover
    Sheet (available on Moodle). No assignment will be accepted or marked if it is not
    accompanied by a signed Cover Sheet with your name, I.D. number, the tutorial
    day/time, and the name of the tutor on the Cover Sheet. An electronic copy will not
    be accepted. You should retain a copy of the work submitted.
    Faculty Style Guide – Work submitted for this assignment must follow the Faculty
    Style as outlined in the Faculty Q Manual. Copies of this manual can be obtained at
    the bookshop or online.
    Applications for extension of time – All applications for an extension of the time
    allocated to an assessment task must be made in writing to the Team Leader (see
    special consideration for within trimester assessment on Moodle). Approval, if
    granted, will be communicated in writing.
    Feedback on Assignment:
    Assignments will be returned during Session One of tutorials in week 12 by a name
    call.
    © Monash College
    Page 2 of 8
    MCD2020 Microeconomics – Research Assignment
    1. Choose any one article from the following articles:
    Harry Potter and the Curse of Market Forces: A muggle's game
    OR
    Of legumes and liberalisation; Brazilian trade
    2. Based on the list of learning objectives,
    a) Identify two (2) microeconomic ideas you can find in the chosen article. Highlight sections
    of the text with those microeconomic ideas, and relate / match those two economic ideas,
    one at a time, to the learning objective given in the appendix. (2 marks for each concept;
    Total 4 marks)
    b) Explain and further discuss the selected economic ideas. In your explanation, you need to
    show understanding of the economic ideas as they are used in the article, by drawing
    connections between the concepts and the article content. Support your discussions with
    relevant diagram(s). (8 marks for each concept; Total 16 marks)
    In your submission, please keep to a limit of 1000 words in total for both concepts.
    3. Attach a copy of the selected article and highlight the parts of the article you have referred to
    in your discussion.
    © Monash College
    Page 3 of 8
    Article 1
    Harry Potter and the Curse of Market Forces: A muggle's game
    The Economist (Online); London (Aug 17, 2016).
    Rather than allowing touts to profit, the play's producers could follow the producers of
    "Hamilton", a wildly successful Broadway musical, and up prices for the premium seats until
    demand falls in line with supply (even at up to $849 per ticket, some argue that "Hamilton"
    is too cheap).
    A British stage show's spellbinding success proves ticket reselling is tough to manage
    TICKETS to "Harry Potter and the Cursed Child", the latest, on‐stage instalment in the
    magically lucrative series, have proved harder to grasp than the golden snitch. After 250,000
    tickets released on August 4th sold out within hours, fans' disappointment turned to
    outrage as stubs with a face value of Pounds 15‐70 ($20‐90) started popping up on resale
    websites for more than Pounds 8,000.
    In line with the howls of outrage, the play's producers called the secondary ticket market an
    "industry‐wide plague" and asserted their contractual right to refuse entry to people turning
    up with a resold ticket. This was the most they could do. Unauthorised reselling (known to
    its foes as scalping) was criminalised in Britain in the case of football in 1994, and in the
    London Olympics of 2012, but is legal for plays and concerts.
    Flint‐hearted economists might note that a secondary market suggests that the seats were
    under‐priced. Cheaper tickets meant to boost equal access lure in touts, for whom low
    prices mean bigger premiums. And more scalpers means more disappointed fans in the
    queue.
    Rather than allowing touts to profit, the play's producers could follow the producers of
    "Hamilton", a wildly successful Broadway musical, and up prices for the premium seats until
    demand falls in line with supply (even at up to $849 per ticket, some argue that "Hamilton"
    is too cheap). But the Potter producers seem to be more worried about impecunious
    wizarding fans losing out than about the prospect of touts swiping surplus.
    Stamping out the secondary market entirely means preventing people selling their tickets to
    those who value them more. This inefficiency is wince‐inducing for economists, and difficult
    to enforce. In May a report on the online secondary ticket market commissioned by the
    government pointed out that banning the secondary market would simply shift activity
    underground.
    Restricting the secondary market is possible, but only with great effort. The government's
    review reported that the Glastonbury model, where festival‐goers must show proof of
    identification alongside their ticket, work, but only because the organisers try so hard to
    control everything, from ticketing to the venue.
    © Monash College
    Page 4 of 8
    Checking at performances of "Harry Potter and the Cursed Child" seems less rigorous. The
    producers have identified only around 60 bookings yielding tickets that that made their way
    on to the secondary market since the play opened in June, an average of around one a day.
    In any case, resale websites guarantee that rejected tickets will be reimbursed. Awkwardly
    for producers, ticket markets are more like unruly bludgers than pliable quaffles.
    (Copyright 2016 The Economist Newspaper Ltd. All rights reserved.)
    © Monash College
    Page 5 of 8
    Article 2

    MCD2020 Microeconomics 微观经济 assignment 代写
    Of legumes and liberalisation; Brazilian trade
    The Economist (Online); London (Jul 2, 2016).
    A big protectionist economy starts to open up.
    FEW Brazilians get through a day without eating beans. They gobble up 3.4m tonnes a year,
    a ladle a day for each person. So when prices rise, as they did by a fifth recently after bad
    weather damaged the domestic harvest, they gripe. On June 24th the government
    suspended its 10% tariff on imports. Blairo Maggi, the agriculture minister, hopes that
    Chinese and Mexican farmers will fill the leguminous gap.
    In a country prone to protectionist folly, Brazil's market‐minded response to the bean
    shortage is refreshing. It may portend a greater opening to trade. Though Brazil is the
    world's ninth‐largest economy, its trade is just 1.2% of the global total; in only five countries
    does trade account for a lower share of GDP. Brazil's new centrist government sees exports
    as one way to pull the country out of its deep recession. Politicians and company bosses are
    starting to regard trade as a way to boost productivity, and thus growth, in the long run,
    too.
    Of late, the government has tucked into liberalisation as if it were an appetising feijoada
    (bean‐and‐meat stew). In April Brazil signed an investment treaty with Peru that, if ratified,
    will allow firms from both countries to compete freely for government contracts. In June
    Brazil asked to join 23 members of the World Trade Organisation (WTO) in negotiating a
    pact on trade in services. The government is preparing legislation to raise the ceiling on
    foreign ownership of airlines from 20%. Mr Maggi talks of lifting a presidential decree from
    2010 that bars foreign ownership of farms, which discourages foreign investors from lending
    to farmers. "All the taboos have gone," says Ricardo
    Mendes of Prospectiva, a consultancy that specialises in trade policy.
    Brazil has been a reluctant globaliser. Ever since the 1950s, when many poor‐country
    governments championed domestic production as a substitute for imports, Brazilian
    industry has been shielded from foreign competition. The left‐wing Workers' Party (PT),
    which governed from 2003 until May this year, continued the cosseting. From 2000 to 2013
    Brazil was a party to a tenth of all disputes filed at the WTO, usually as the plaintiff. During
    that period it erected more trade barriers‐‐from tariffs to subsidies to local‐content rules‐‐
    than most other countries.
    Attitudes started to shift in 2012 as the economy weakened, prompting firms to seek
    growth abroad. Dilma Rousseff, the PT president, began to liberalise trade after her re‐
    election in 2014. The government has enacted two dozen pro‐trade measures and just three
    restrictive ones since the start of 2015, according to the WTO.
    Michel Temer, who became acting president in May after Ms Rousseff was forced to step
    aside while the Senate conducts an impeachment trial against her, is going further. Although
    his Party of the Brazilian Democratic Movement is close to competition‐shy industry, he has
    © Monash College
    Page 6 of 8
    a liberal streak. He plans to dismantle local‐content rules in the oil‐and‐gas sector (which
    force companies to use substandard, and often more expensive, domestic technology). He
    replaced Ms Rousseff's liberalising trade minister but kept the ministry's technocrats to
    avoid disrupting negotiations.
    On June 24th Mr Temer renewed a bilateral automotive arrangement with Argentina for
    four years (rather than the usual one). For the first time the two countries, the main
    constituents of Mercosur, a South American trade group, have agreed in principle to free
    trade in cars and car parts from 2020. Brazil's new trade minister, Marcos Pereira, wants to
    conclude an ambitious trade deal with Mexico by the end of 2016. Mr Temer took Apex, the
    export promotion agency, away from Mr Pereira and gave it to the foreign minister, Jose
    Serra, an economist. It has a new mission, "inserting Brazil into global supply chains", which
    implies greater openness to imports.
    Curb your enthusiasm.
    Brazil opened partially in the early 1990s but later attempts to liberalise fizzled. The
    government of Fernando Henrique Cardoso signed ten bilateral investment treaties in the
    late 1990s and ratified none. A Free‐Trade Area of the Americas, supported by Mr Cardoso,
    was blocked by his successor. Industries will not give up protection without a fight.
    Another worry is that Brazil's move towards openness comes at a time when its biggest
    trading partners are moving in the opposite direction. It is safe to say that the European
    Union's first priority will not now be to conclude its trade deal with Mercosur. One
    presidential candidate in the United States is a raging protectionist; the other is ambivalent.
    This makes Brazil's change of attitude all the more welcome. Brazilian businesses will not
    become competitive unless they compete, acknowledges Mr Maggi. It has taken Brazil a
    long time to learn that lesson.
    (Copyright 2016 The Economist Newspaper Ltd. All rights reserved.)
    © Monash College
    Page 7 of 8

    MCD2020 Microeconomics 微观经济 assignment 代写
    MCD2020 Microeconomics ‐ List of Learning Objectives
    1. Understand the factors that influence the demand for goods and services.
    2. Understand the factors that influence the supply of goods and services.
    3. Explain how equilibrium in a market is reached and use a graph to illustrate equilibrium.
    4. Use demand and supply graphs to predict changes in prices and quantities
    5. Define the price elasticity of demand and understand how to calculate it.
    6. Understand the determinants of the price elasticity of demand.
    7. Understand the relationship between the price elasticity of demand and total revenue.
    8. Define the cross‐price elasticity of demand and the income elasticity of demand, and understand
    their determinants and how they are calculated.
    9. Use price elasticity and income elasticity to analyse economic issues.
    10. Define the elasticity of supply, and understand its main determinants and how it is calculated.
    11. Understand the concepts of consumer surplus and producer surplus.
    12. Understand the concept of economic efficiency, and use a graph to illustrate how economic
    efficiency is reduced when a market is not in competitive equilibrium. 
    13. Use demand and supply graphs to analyse the economic impact of price ceilings and price floors.
    14. Use demand and supply graphs to analyse the economic impact of taxes and subsidies
    15. Explain how firms choose the profit‐maximising quantity of labour.
    16. Explain how people choose the quantity of labour to supply.
    17. Explain how equilibrium wages are determined in labour markets.
    18. Explain how countries gain from international trade.
    19. Describe the winners and losers with exports and imports.
    20. Analyse the economic effects of policies that restrict trade.
    21. Evaluate the arguments for and against government policies that restrict international trade.
    22. Understand the defining characteristics of public goods and common resources
    23. Examine why private markets fail to provide public goods
    24. Explain why externalities can make market outcomes inefficient
    25. Examine how people can sometimes solve the problem of externalities on their own
    26. Examine the various government policies aimed at solving the problem of externalities
    27. Examine what items are included in a firm’s costs of production
    28. Analyse the link between a firm’s production process and its total costs
    29. Understand the meaning of average total cost and marginal cost and how they are related
    30. Consider the shape of a typical firm’s cost curves
    31. Examine the relationship between short‐run and long‐run costs.
    32. Define a perfectly competitive market, and explain why a perfect competitor faces a horizontal
    demand curve.
    33. Explain how a perfect competitor decides how much to produce.
    34. Use graphs to show a firm’s profit or loss. 
    35. Explain why firms may shut down temporarily.
    36. Explain how entry and exit ensure that firms earn zero economic profit in the long run.
    37. Explain how perfect competition leads to economic efficiency.
    © Monash College
    Page 8 of 8
    Marking Rubrics
      1 mark  2 marks  3 marks  4 marks
    Identify
    (2 marks max.)
    Fair
    Vague
    identification
    Good
    Clear
    identification
      
    Explain
    (4 marks max.)
    to showing
    understanding of
    learning
    objectives
    Poor
    Brief
    presentation, but
    does not show
    much
    understanding
    Fair
    Fairly well
    presented, but
    lacking in details
    Good
    Sufficiently
    detailed
    presentation,
    with some
    reference to
    article content
    Excellent
    Comprehensive
    presentation of
    answer, with
    references to
    article content,
    integrated into
    explanation
    Further Discuss
    (4 marks max.)
    further by
    making the
    connection
    between the
    concepts/ideas in
    the article, and
    support your
    discussion with
    relevant
    diagram(s).
    Poor
    Brief answer, but
    does not show
    much
    understanding
    Fair
    Fairly well
    written, but
    lacking in details
    with somewhat
    unclear
    diagram(s)
    Good
    Sufficiently
    detailed answer,
    supported by
    well‐labelled
    diagram(s)
    Excellent
    Comprehensive
    answer,
    supported by
    relevant and fully
    labelled
    diagram(s)
    MCD2020 Microeconomics 微观经济 assignment 代写